No Spice and Little Gold
October 14, 2014Adam Smith |
Adam Smith.
(1723–1790). Wealth of Nations.
Vol. 10, pp. 395-404 of
The Harvard Classics
All colonies are
founded to gain territory or treasure. Spain expected spice and gold
from Columbus's expedition, but got no spice and little gold. Adam
Smith tells the true motive of the colonizing Greeks, Romans,
English, and Spaniards.
Book IV
VII. Of
Colonies
PART I.
OF THE MOTIVES FOR ESTABLISHING NEW COLONIES
THE INTEREST which occasioned the first settlement of the different European colonies in America and the West Indies, was not altogether so plain and distinct as that which directed the establishment of those of ancient Greece and Rome.
All the
different states of ancient Greece possessed, each of them, but a
very small territory, and when the people in any one of them
multiplied beyond what that territory could easily maintain, a part
of them were sent in quest of a new habitation in some remote and
distant part of the world; the warlike neighbours who surrounded them
on all sides, rendering it difficult for any of them to enlarge very
much its territory at home. The colonies of the Dorians resorted
chiefly to Italy and Sicily, which, in the times preceding the
foundation of Rome, were inhabited by barbarous and uncivilized
nations: those of the Ionians and Eolians, the two other great tribes
of the Greeks, to Asia Minor and the islands of the Egean Sea, of
which the inhabitants seem at that time to have been pretty much in
the same state as those of Sicily and Italy. The mother city, though
she considered the colony as a child, at all times entitled to great
favour and assistance, and owing in return much gratitude and
respect, yet considered it as an emancipated child, over whom she
pretended to claim no direct authority or jurisdiction. The colony
settled its own form of government, enacted its own laws, elected its
own magistrates, and made peace or war with its neighbours as an
independent state, which had no occasion to wait for the approbation
or consent of the mother city. Nothing can be more plain and distinct
than the interest which directed every such establishment.
Rome, like
most of the other ancient republics, was originally founded upon an
Agrarian law, which divided the public territory in a certain
proportion among the different citizens who composed the state. The
course of human affairs, by marriage, by succession, and by
alienation, necessarily deranged this original division, and
frequently threw the lands, which had been allotted for the
maintenance of many different families into the possession of a
single person. To remedy this disorder, for such it was supposed to
be, a law was made, restricting the quantity of land which any
citizen could possess to five hundred jugera, about three hundred and
fifty English acres. This law, however, though we read of its having
been executed upon one or two occasions, was either neglected or
evaded, and the inequality of fortunes went on continually
increasing. The greater part of the citizens had no land, and without
it the manners and customs of those times rendered it difficult for a
freeman to maintain his independency. In the present times, though a
poor man has no land of his own, if he has a little stock, he may
either farm the lands of another, or he may carry on some little
retail trade; and if he has no stock, he may find employment either
as a country labourer, or as an artificer. But, among the ancient
Romans, the lands of the rich were all cultivated by slaves, who
wrought under an overseer, who was likewise a slave; so that a poor
freeman had little chance of being employed either as a farmer or as
a labourer. All trades and manufactures too, even the retail trade,
were carried on by the slaves of the rich for the benefit of their
masters, whose wealth, authority, and protection made it difficult
for a poor freeman to maintain the competition against them. The
citizens, therefore, who had no land, had scarce any other means of
subsistence but the bounties of the candidates at the annual
elections. The tribunes, when they had a mind to animate the people
against the rich and the great, put them in mind of the ancient
division of lands, and represented that law which restricted this
sort of private property as the fundamental law of the republic. The
people became clamorous to get land, and the rich and the great, we
may believe, were perfectly determined not to give them any part of
theirs. To satisfy them in some measure, therefore, they frequently
proposed to send out a new colony. But conquering Rome was, even upon
such occasions, under no necessity of turning out her citizens to
seek their fortune, if one may say so, through the wide world,
without knowing where they were to settle. She assigned them lands
generally in the conquered provinces of Italy, where, being within
the dominions of the republic, they could never form any independent
state; but were at best but a sort of corporation, which, though it
had the power of enacting bye-laws for its own government, was at all
times subject to the correction, jurisdiction, and legislative
authority of the mother city. The sending out a colony of this kind,
not only gave some satisfaction to the people, but often established
a sort of garrison too in a newly conquered province, of which the
obedience might otherwise have been doubtful. A Roman colony,
therefore, whether we consider the nature of the establishment
itself, or the motives for making it, was altogether different from a
Greek one. The words accordingly, which in the original languages
denote those different establishments, have very different meanings.
The Latin word (Colonia) signifies simply a plantation. The
Greek word ([Greek]), on the contrary, signifies a separation of
dwelling, a departure from home, a going out of the house. But,
though the Roman colonies were in many respects different from the
Greek ones, the interest which prompted to establish them was equally
plain and distinct. Both institutions derived their origin either
from irresistible necessity, or from clear and evident utility.
The
establishment of the European colonies in America and the West Indies
arose from no necessity: and though the utility which has resulted
from them has been very great, it is not altogether so clear and
evident. It was not understood at their first establishment, and was
not the motive either of that establishment or of the discoveries
which gave occasion to it; and the nature, extent, and limits of that
utility are not, perhaps, well understood at this day.
The
Venetians, during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, carried on
a very advantageous commerce in spiceries, and other East India
goods, which they distributed among the other nations of Europe. They
purchased them chiefly in Egypt, at that time under the dominion of
the Mammeluks, the enemies of the Turks, of whom the Venetians were
the enemies; and this union of interest, assisted by the money of
Venice, formed such a connection as gave the Venetians almost a
monopoly of the trade.
The great
profits of the Venetians tempted the avidity of the Portuguese. They
had been endeavouring, during the course of the fifteenth century, to
find out by sea a way to the countries from which the Moors brought
them ivory and gold dust across the Desert. They discovered the
Madeiras, the Canaries, the Azores, the Cape de Verd islands, the
coast of Guinea, that of Loango, Congo, Angola, and Benguela, and
finally, the Cape of Good Hope. They had long wished to share in the
profitable traffic of the Venetians, and this last discovery opened
to them a probable prospect of doing so. In 1497, Vasco de Gama
sailed from the port of Lisbon with a fleet of four ships, and, after
a navigation of eleven months, arrived upon the coast of Indostan,
and thus completed a course of discoveries which had been pursued
with great steadiness, and with very little interruption, for near a
century together.
Some years
before this, while the expectations of Europe were in suspense about
the projects of the Portuguese, of which the success appeared yet to
be doubtful, a Genoese pilot formed the yet more daring project of
sailing to the East Indies by the West. The situation of those
countries was at that time very imperfectly known in Europe. The few
European travellers who had been there had magnified the distance;
perhaps through simplicity and ignorance, what was really very great,
appearing almost infinite to those who could not measure it; or,
perhaps, in order to increase somewhat more the marvellous of their
own adventures in visiting regions so immensely remote from Europe.
The longer the way was by the East, Columbus very justly concluded,
the shorter it would be by the West. He proposed, therefore, to take
that way, as both the shortest and the surest, and he had the good
fortune to convince Isabella of Castile of the probability of his
project. He sailed from the port of Palos in August, 1492, near five
years before the expedition of Vasco de Gama set out from Portugal,
and, after a voyage of between two and three months, discovered first
some of the small Bahama or Lucayan islands, and afterwards the great
island of St. Domingo.
But the
countries which Columbus discovered, either in this or in any of his
subsequent voyages, had no resemblance to those which he had gone in
quest of. Instead of the wealth, cultivation and populousness of
China and Indostan, he found, in St. Domingo, and in all the other
parts of the new world which he ever visited, nothing but a country
quite covered with wood, uncultivated, and inhabited only by some
tribes of naked and miserable savages. He was not very willing,
however, to believe that they were not the same with some of the
countries described by Marco Polo, the first European who had
visited, or at least had left behind him any description of China or
the East Indies; and a very slight resemblance, such as that which he
found between the name of Cibao, a mountain in St. Domingo, and that
of Cipango, mentioned by Marco Polo, was frequently sufficient to
make him return to this favourite prepossession, though contrary to
the clearest evidence. In his letters to Ferdinand and Isabella he
called the countries which he had discovered, the Indies. He
entertained no doubt but that they were the extremity of those which
had been described by Marco Polo, and that they were not very distant
from the Ganges, or from the countries which had been conquered by
Alexander. Even when at last convinced that they were different, he
still flattered himself that those rich countries were at no great
distance, and in a subsequent voyage, accordingly, went in quest of
them along the coast of Terra Firma, and towards the isthmus of
Darien.
In
consequence of this mistake of Columbus, the name of the Indies has
stuck to those unfortunate countries ever since; and when it was at
last clearly discovered that the new were altogether different from
the old Indies, the former were called the West, in contradistinction
to the latter, which were called the East Indies.
It was of
importance to Columbus, however, that the countries which he had
discovered, whatever they were, should be represented to the court of
Spain as of very great consequence; and, in what constitutes the real
riches of every country, the animal and vegetable productions of the
soil, there was at that time nothing which could well justify such a
representation of them.
The Cori,
something between a rat and a rabbit, and supposed by Mr. Buffon to
be the same with the Aperea of Brazil, was the largest viviparous
quadruped in St. Domingo. This species seems never to have been very
numerous, and the dogs and cats of the Spaniards are said to have
long ago almost entirely extirpated it, as well as some other tribes
of a still smaller size. These, however, together with a pretty large
lizard, called the Ivana or Iguana, constituted the principal part of
the animal food which the land afforded.
The
vegetable food of the inhabitants, though from their want of industry
not very abundant, was not altogether so scanty. It consisted in
Indian corn, yams, potatoes, bananas, &c. plants which were then
altogether unknown in Europe, and which have never since been very
much esteemed in it, or supposed to yield a sustenance equal to what
is drawn from the common sorts of grain and pulse, which have been
cultivated in this part of the world time out of mind.
The cotton
plant indeed afforded the material of a very important manufacture,
and was at that time to Europeans undoubtedly the most valuable of
all the vegetable productions of those islands. But though in the end
of the fifteenth century the muslins and other cotton goods of the
East Indies were much esteemed in every part of Europe, the cotton
manufacture itself was not cultivated in any part of it. Even this
production, therefore, could not at that time appear in the eyes of
Europeans to be of very great consequence.
Finding
nothing either in the animals or vegetables of the newly discovered
countries, which could justify a very advantageous representation of
them, Columbus turned his view towards their minerals; and in the
richness of the production of this third kingdom, he flattered
himself, he had found a full compensation for the insignificancy of
those of the other two. The little bits of gold with which the
inhabitants ornamented their dress, and which, he was informed, they
frequently found in the rivulets and torrents that fell from the
mountains, were sufficient to satisfy him that those mountains
abounded with the riches to gold mines. St. Domingo, therefore, was
represented as a country abounding with gold, and, upon that account
(according to the prejudices not only of the present times, but of
those times), an inexhaustible source of real wealth to the crown and
kingdom of Spain. When Columbus, upon his return from his first
voyage, was introduced with a sort of triumphal honours to the
sovereigns of Castile and Arragon, the principal productions of the
countries which he had discovered were carried in solemn procession
before him. The only valuable part of them consisted in some little
fillets, bracelets, and other ornaments of gold, and in some bales of
cotton. The rest were mere objects of vulgar wonder and curiosity;
some reeds of an extraordinary size, some birds of a very beautiful
plumage, and some stuffed skins of the huge alligator and manati; all
of which were preceded by six or seven of the wretched natives, whose
singular colour and appearance added greatly to the novelty of the
shew.
In
consequence of the representations of Columbus, the council of
Castile determined to take possession of countries of which the
inhabitants were plainly incapable of defending themselves. The pious
purpose of converting them to Christianity sanctified the injustice
of the project. But the hope of finding treasures of gold there, was
the sole motive which prompted to undertake it; and to give this
motive the greater weight, it was proposed by Columbus that the half
of all the gold and silver that should be found there should belong
to the crown. This proposal was approved of by the council.
As long as
the whole or the far greater part of the gold, which the first
adventurers imported into Europe, was got by so very easy a method as
the plundering of the defenceless natives, it was not perhaps very
difficult to pay even this heavy tax. But when the natives were once
fairly stript of all that they had, which, in St. Domingo, and in all
the other countries discovered by Columbus, was done completely in
six or eight years, and when in order to find more it had become
necessary to dig for it in the mines, there was no longer any
possibility of paying this tax. The rigorous exaction of it,
accordingly, first occasioned, it is said, the total abandoning of
the mines of St. Domingo, which have never been wrought since. It was
soon reduced therefore to a third; then to a fifth; afterwards to a
tenth; and at last to a twentieth part of the gross produce of the
gold mines. The tax upon silver continued for a long time to be a
fifth of the gross produce. It was reduced to a tenth only in the
course of the present century. But the first adventurers do not
appear to have been much interested about silver. Nothing less
precious than gold seemed worthy of their attention.
All the
other enterprises of the Spaniards in the new world, subsequent to
those of Columbus, seem to have been prompted by the same motive. It
was the sacred thirst of gold that carried Oieda, Nicuessa, and Vasco
Nugnes de Balboa, to the isthmus of Darien, that carried Cortez to
Mexico, and Almagro and Pizzarro to Chili and Peru. When those
adventurers arrived upon any unknown coast, their first enquiry was
always if there was any gold to be found there; and according to the
information which they received concerning this particular, they
determined either to quit the country or to settle in it.
Of all
those expensive and uncertain projects, however, which bring
bankruptcy upon the greater part of the people who engage in them,
there is none perhaps more perfectly ruinous than the search after
new silver and gold mines. It is perhaps the most disadvantageous
lottery in the world, or the one in which the gain of those who draw
the prizes bears the least proportion to the loss of those who draw
the blanks; for though the prizes are few and the blanks many, the
common price of a ticket is the whole fortune of a very rich man.
Projects of mining, instead of replacing the capital employed in
them, together with the ordinary profits of stock, commonly absorb
both capital and profit. They are the projects, therefore, to which
of all others a prudent law-giver, who desired to increase the
capital of his nation, would least chuse to give any extraordinary
encouragement, or to turn towards them a greater share of that
capital than what would go to them of its own accord. Such in reality
is the absurd confidence which almost all men have in their own good
fortune, that wherever there is the least probability of success, too
great a share of it is apt to go to them of its own accord.
But though
the judgment of sober reason and experience concerning such projects
has always been extremely unfavourable, that of human avidity has
commonly been quite otherwise. The same passion which has suggested
to so’ many people the absurd idea of the philosopher’s stone,
has suggested to others the equally absurd one of immense rich mines
of gold and silver. They did not consider that the value of those
metals has, in all ages and nations, arisen chiefly from their
scarcity, and that their scarcity has arisen from the very small
quantities of them which nature has any where deposited in one place,
from the hard and intractable substances with which she has almost
every where surrounded those small quantities, and consequently from
the labour and expence which are every where necessary in order to
penetrate to and get at them. They flattered themselves that veins of
those metals might in many places be found as large and as abundant
as those which are commonly found of lead, or copper, or tin, or
iron. The dream of Sir Walter Raleigh concerning the golden city and
country of Eldorado, may satisfy us, that even wise men are not
always exempt from such strange delusions. More than a hundred years
after the death of that great man, the Jesuit Gumila was still
convinced of the reality of that wonderful country, and expressed
with great warmth, and I dare to say, with great sincerity, how happy
he should be to carry the light of the gospel to a people who could
so well reward the pious labours of their missionary.
In the
countries first discovered by the Spaniards, no gold or silver mines
are at present known which are supposed to be worth the working. The
quantities of those metals which the first adventurers are said to
have found there, had probably been very much magnified, as well as
the fertility of the mines which were wrought immediately after the
first discovery. What those adventures were reported to have found,
however, was sufficient to inflame the avidity of all their
countrymen. Every Spaniard who sailed to America expected to find an
Eldorado. Fortune too did upon this what she has done upon very few
other occasions. She realized in some measure the extravagant hopes
of her votaries, and in the discovery and conquest of Mexico and Peru
(of which the one happened about thirty, the other about forty years
after the first expedition of Columbus), she presented them with
something not very unlike that profusion of the precious metals which
they sought for.
A project
of commerce to the East Indies, therefore, gave occasion to the first
discovery of the West. A project of conquest gave occasion to all the
establishments of the Spaniards in those newly discovered countries.
The motive which excited them to this conquest was a project of gold
and silver mines; and a course of accidents, which no human wisdom
could foresee, rendered this project much more successful than the
undertakers had any reasonable grounds for expecting.
The first
adventurers of all the other nations of Europe, who attempted to make
settlements in America, were animated by the like chimerical views;
but they were not equally successful. It was more than a hundred
years after the first settlement of the Brazils, before any silver,
gold, or diamond mines were discovered there. In the English, French,
Dutch, and Danish colonies, none have ever yet been discovered; at
least none that are at present supposed to be worth the working. The
first English settlers in North America, however, offered a fifth of
all the gold and silver which should be found there to the king, as a
motive for granting them their patents. In the patents to Sir Walter
Raleigh, to the London and Plymouth companies, to the council of
Plymouth, &c. this fifth was accordingly reserved to the crown.
To the expectation of finding gold and silver mines, those first
settlers too joined that of discovering a north-west passage to the
East Indies. They have hitherto been disappointed in both.
0 comments