They Had No Money - Yet Bought and Sold
May 24, 2020The Wealth of Nations |
Adam Smith.
(1723–1790). Wealth of Nations.
Vol. 10, pp.27-33 of
The Harvard Classics
Debts were not
always paid in money. Not so long ago the butcher paid for his keg of
beer with a slab of beef, and oxen were exchanged for land and wives.
Adam Smith tells the interesting story of the origin and use of
money.
Book I
IV. Of
the Origin and Use of Money
WHEN the division of
labour has been once thoroughly established, it is but a very small
part of a man’s wants which the produce of his own labour can
supply. He supplies the far greater part of them by exchanging that
surplus part of the produce of his own labour, which is over and
above his own consumption, for such parts of the produce of other
men’s labour as he has occasion for. Every man thus lives by
exchanging, or becomes in some measure a merchant, and the society
itself grows to be what is properly a commercial society.
But when the division of labour first
began to take place, this power of exchanging must frequently have
been very much clogged and embarrassed in its operations. One man, we
shall suppose, has more of a certain commodity than he himself has
occasion for, while another has less. The former consequently would
be glad to dispose of, and the latter to purchase, a part of this
superfluity. But if this latter should chance to have nothing that
the former stands in need of, no exchange can be made between them.
The butcher has more meat in his shop than he himself can consume,
and the brewer and the baker would each of them be willing to
purchase a part of it. But they have nothing to offer in exchange,
except the different productions of their respective trades, and the
butcher is already provided with all the bread and beer which he has
immediate occasion for. No exchange can, in this case, be made
between them. He cannot be their merchant, nor they his customers;
and they are all of them thus mutually less serviceable to one
another. In order to avoid the inconveniency of such situations,
every prudent man in every period of society, after the first
establishment of the division of labour, must naturally have
endeavoured to manage his affairs in such a manner, as to have at all
times by him, besides the peculiar produce of his own industry, a
certain quantity of some one commodity or other, such as he imagined
few people would be likely to refuse in exchange for the produce of
their industry.
Many different commodities, it is
probable, were successively both thought of and employed for this
purpose. In the rude ages of society, cattle are said to have been
the common instrument of commerce; and, though they must have been a
most inconvenient one, yet in old times we find things were
frequently valued according to the number of cattle which had been
given in exchange for them. The armour of Diomede, says Homer, cost
only nine oxen; but that of Glaucus cost an hundred oxen. Salt is
said to be the common instrument of commerce and exchanges in
Abyssinia; a species of shells in some parts of the coast of India;
dried cod at Newfoundland; tobacco in Virginia; sugar in some of our
West India colonies; hides or dressed leather in some other
countries; and there is at this day a village in Scotland where it is
not uncommon, I am told, for a workman to carry nails instead of
money to the baker’s shop or the alehouse.
In all countries, however, men seem at
last to have been determined by irresistible reasons to give the
preference, for this employment, to metals above every other
commodity. Metals can not only be kept with as little loss as any
other commodity, scarce any thing being less perishable than they
are, but they can likewise, without any loss, be divided into any
number of parts, as by fusion those parts can easily be reunited
again; a quality which no other equally durable commodities possess,
and which more than any other quality renders them fit to be the
instruments of commerce and circulation. The man who wanted to buy
salt, for example, and had nothing but cattle to give in exchange for
it, must have been obliged to buy salt to the value of a whole ox, or
a whole sheep, at a time. He could seldom buy less than this, because
what he was to give for it could seldom be divided without loss; and
if he had a mind to buy more, he must, for the same reasons, have
been obliged to buy double or triple the quantity, the value, to wit,
of two or three oxen, or of two or three sheep. If on the contrary,
instead of sheep or oxen, he had metals to give in exchange for it,
he could easily proportion the quantity of the metal to the precise
quantity of the commodity which he had immediate occasion for.
Different metals have been made use of
by different nations for this purpose. Iron was the common instrument
of commerce among the antient Spartans; copper among the antient
Romans; and gold and silver among all rich commercial nations.
Those metals seem originally to have
been made use of for this purpose in rude bars, without any stamp or
coinage. Thus we are told by Pliny, upon the authority of Timæus, an
antient historian, that, till the time of Servius Tullius, the Romans
had no coined money, but made use of unstamped bars of copper, to
purchase whatever they had occasion for. These rude bars, therefore,
performed at this time the function of money.
The use of metals in this rude state
was attended with two very considerable inconveniences; first with
the trouble of weighing; and, secondly, with that of assaying them.
In the precious metals, where a small difference in the quantity
makes a great difference in the value, even the business of weighing,
with proper exactness, requires at least very accurate weights and
scales. The weighing of gold in particular is an operation of some
nicety. In the coarser metals, indeed, where a small error would be
of little consequence, less accuracy would, no doubt, be necessary.
Yet we should find it excessively troublesome, if every time a poor
man had occasion either to buy or sell a farthing’s worth of goods,
he was obliged to weigh the farthing. The operation of assaying is
still more difficult, still more tedious, and, unless a part of the
metal is fairly melted in the crucible, with proper dissolvents, any
conclusion that can be drawn from it, is extremely uncertain. Before
the institution of coined money, however, unless they went through
this tedious and difficult operation, people must always have been
liable to the grossest frauds and impositions, and instead of a pound
weight of pure silver, or pure copper, might receive in exchange for
their goods, an adulterated composition of the coarsest and cheapest
materials, which had, however, in their outward appearance, been made
to resemble those metals. To prevent such abuses, to facilitate
exchanges, and thereby to encourage all sorts of industry and
commerce, it has been found necessary, in all countries that have
made any considerable advances towards improvement, to affix a public
stamp upon certain quantities of such particular metals, as were in
those countries commonly made use of to purchase goods. Hence the
origin of coined money, and of those public offices called mints;
institutions exactly of the same nature with those of the aulnagers
and stampmasters of woollen and linen cloth. All of them are equally
meant to ascertain, by means of a public stamp, the quantity and
uniform goodness of those different commodities when brought to
market.
The first public stamps of this kind
that were affixed to the current metals, seem in many cases to have
been intended to ascertain, what it was both most difficult and most
important to ascertain, the goodness or fineness of the metal, and to
have resembled the sterling mark which is at present affixed to plate
and bars of silver, or the Spanish mark which is sometimes affixed to
ingots of gold, and which being struck only upon one side of the
piece, and not covering the whole surface, ascertains the fineness,
but not the weight of the metal. Abraham weighs to Ephron the four
hundred shekels of silver which he had agreed to pay for the field of
Machpelah. They are said, however, to be the current money of the
merchant, and yet are received by weight and not by tale, in the same
manner as ingots of gold and bars of silver are at present. The
revenues of the antient Saxon kings of England are said to have been
paid, not in money but in kind, that is, in victuals and provisions
of all sorts. William the Conqueror introduced the custom of paying
them in money. This money, however, was, for a long time, received at
the exchequer, by weight and not by tale.
The inconveniency and difficulty of
weighing those metals with exactness gave occasion to the institution
of coins, of which the stamp, covering entirely both sides of the
piece and sometimes the edges too, was supposed to ascertain not only
the fineness, but the weight of the metal. Such coins, therefore,
were received by tale as at present, without the trouble of weighing.
The denominations of those coins seem
originally to have expressed the weight or quantity of metal
contained in them. In the time of Servius Tullius, who first coined
money at Rome, the Roman As or Pondo contained a Roman pound of good
copper. It was divided in the same manner as our Troyes pound, into
twelve ounces, each of which contained a real ounce of good copper.
The English pound sterling in the time of Edward I., contained a
pound, Tower weight, of silver of a known fineness. The Tower pound
seems to have been something more than the Roman pound, and something
less than the Troyes pound. This last was not introduced into the
mint of England till the 18th of Henry VIII. The French livre
contained in the time of Charlemagne a pound, Troyes weight, of
silver of a known fineness. The fair of Troyes in Champaign was at
that time frequented by all the nations of Europe, and the weights
and measures of so famous a market were generally known and esteemed.
The Scots money pound contained, from the time of Alexander the First
to that of Robert Bruce, a pound of silver of the same weight and
fineness with the English pound sterling. English, French, and Scots
pennies too, contained all of them originally a real pennyweight of
silver, the twentieth part of an ounce, and the
two-hundred-and-fortieth part of a pound. The shilling, too, seems
originally to have been the denomination of a weight. When
wheat is at twelve shillings the quarter, says an antient
statute of Henry III., then wastel bread of a farthing shall
weigh eleven shillings and four pence. The proportion,
however, between the shilling and either the penny on the one hand,
or the pound on the other, seems not to have been so constant and
uniform as that between the penny and the pound. During the first
race of the kings of France, the French sou or shilling appears upon
different occasions to have contained five, twelve, twenty, and forty
pennies. Among the antient Saxons a shilling appears at one time to
have contained only five pennies, and it is not improbable that it
may have been as variable among them as among their neighbours, the
antient Franks. From the time of Charlemagne among the French, and
from that of William the Conqueror among the English, the proportion
between the pound, the shilling, and the penny, seems to have been
uniformly the same as at present, though the value of each has been
very different. For in every country of the world, I believe, the
avarice and injustice of princes and sovereign states, abusing the
confidence of their subjects, have by degrees diminished the real
quantity of metal, which had been originally contained in their
coins. The Roman As, in the latter ages of the Republic, was reduced
to the twenty-fourth part of its original value, and, instead of
weighing a pound, came to weigh only half an ounce. The English pound
and penny contain at present about a third only; the Scots pound and
penny about a thirty-sixth; and the French pound and penny about a
sixty-sixth part of their original value. By means of those
operations the princes and sovereign states which performed them were
enabled, in appearance, to pay their debts and to fulfil their
engagements with a smaller quantity of silver than would otherwise
have been requisite. It was indeed in appearance only; for their
creditors were really defrauded of a part of what was due to them.
All other debtors in the state were allowed the same privilege, and
might pay with the same nominal sum of the new and debased coin
whatever they had borrowed in the old. Such operations, therefore,
have always proved favourable to the debtor, and ruinous to the
creditor, and have sometimes produced a greater and more universal
revolution in the fortunes of private persons, than could have been
occasioned by a very great public calamity.
It is in this manner that money has
become in all civilized nations the universal instrument of commerce,
by the intervention of which goods of all kinds are bought and sold,
or exchanged for one another.
What are the rules which men naturally
observe in exchanging them either for money or for one another, I
shall now proceed to examine. These rules determine what may be
called the relative or exchangeable value of goods.
The word VALUE, it
is to be observed, has two different meanings, and sometimes
expresses the utility of some particular object, and sometimes the
power of purchasing other goods which the possession of that object
conveys. The one may be called “value in use;” the other, “value
in exchange.” The things which have the greatest value in use have
frequently little or no value in exchange; and on the contrary, those
which have the greatest value in exchange have frequently little or
no value in use. Nothing is more useful than water: but it will
purchase scarce any thing; scarce any thing can be had in exchange
for it. A diamond, on the contrary, has scarce any value in use; but
a very great quantity of other goods may frequently be had in
exchange for it.
In order to investigate the principles
which regulate the exchangeable value of commodities, I shall
endeavour to shew,
First, what is the real measure of
this exchangeable value; or, wherein consists the real price of all
commodities.
Secondly, what are the different parts
of which this real price is composed or made up.
And, lastly, what are the different
circumstances which sometimes raise some or all of these different
parts of price above, and sometimes sink them below their natural or
ordinary rate; or, what are the causes which sometimes hinder the
market price, that is, the actual price of commodities, from
coinciding exactly with what may be called their natural price.
I shall endeavour to explain, as fully
and distinctly as I can, those three subjects in the three following
chapters, for which I must very earnestly entreat both the patience
and attention of the reader: his patience in order to examine a
detail which may perhaps in some places appear unnecessarily tedious;
and his attention in order to understand what may, perhaps, after the
fullest explication which I am capable of giving of it, appear still
in some degree obscure. I am always willing to run some hazard of
being tedious in order to be sure that I am perspicuous; and after
taking the utmost pains that I can to be perspicuous, some obscurity
may still appear to remain upon a subject in its own nature extremely
abstracted.
0 comments